Main index Electoral System index About author

Valid HTML 4.01 Transitional

PR-Squared and the 2015 General Election

Julian D. A. Wiseman

Abstract: This paper contains a description of PR-Squared, which is a new electoral system that typically elects a majority government; that elects one local MP from each constituency each of whom is dependent on the local vote; yet that still ensures that equal votes mean equal seats. Hence it has the advantages of first-past-the-post, and the ‘fairness’ of proportional representation.

twitter

Publication history: Only at www.jdawiseman.com/papers/electsys/pr2_2015.html. Usual disclaimer and copyright terms apply.


Facebook icon

There is a PR² group on Facebook. This was not created by, nor is it controlled nor endorsed by, the author, who is not a member of Facebook. Nonetheless, its existence might be of interest to some readers.

PR-Squared: how it works

PR-Squared is a new electoral system designed for the UK’s House of Commons. It typically elects a majority government; it elects one local MP from each constituency each of whom is dependent on the local vote; yet it still ensures that equal votes mean equal seats and that fewer votes cannot mean more seats.

PR-Squared works as follows.

We start with a simple example with only three parties and seven constituencies, in which votes are as follows:

 PalatineCapitolineAventineCælianEsquilineViminalQuirinalTotals
Red655324328
Blue432550120
Yellow002116414
Totals10899810862

The number of seats each party has won is calculated from the parties’ nation-wide vote totals: 28, 20 and 14. The seven seats are allocated proportional to the squares of these, giving an unrounded allocation of 3.98, 2.03 and 0.99, and hence a rounded allocation of 4, 2 and 1.

But which party has won which seat? Let’s guess. If Red were allocated the first four seats (Palatine, Capitoline, Aventine and Cælian), Blue the next two (Esquiline and Viminal), and Yellow the last (Quirinal), then 28 voters across the nation would have voted for their MP. We say that, under this seat assignment, 28 voters are ‘happy’. PR-Squared allocates seats by maximising happiness. A computerised algorithm quickly shows that the maximum happiness is 35: Red wins Palatine, Capitoline, Aventine and Quirinal; Blue takes Cælian and Esquiline; and Yellow wins Viminal.

We bring this into the table, along with the First-Past-The-Post winner:

 PalatineCapitolineAventineCælianEsquilineViminalQuirinalTotals
Red655324328
Blue432550120
Yellow002116414
Totals10899810862
FPTP
winner
RedRedRedBlueBlueYellowYellow3:2:2
PR²
winner
RedRedRedBlueBlueYellowRed4:2:1

Observe that:

1983 and 2015 UK general elections

Let’s consider an actual election result. In the UK 1983 general election the vote for the three large parties split 44.5% to 28.9% to 26.6%. Seats would have been allocated in proportion to the squares of these numbers: 1980.25, 835.21 and 707.56. Scaling the ratio of the squares so that they total 650 seats gives 365.4, 154.1 and 130.5, which round to an actual seat allocation of 365, 154 and 131: a majority of 80 for the largest party†2. Note that equal votes give equal seats, and nearly equal votes give nearly equal seats (unlike the first-past-the-post, in which the second-largest party received 1.09× as many votes as the third largest, but 9× as many seats).

As a further example, the following table uses data from the UK general election in May 2015.

Party Votes Votes^2
(billions)
PR² seats
unrounded
PR² seats
rounded
FPTP
seats
PR²−
FPTP
seats
Votes÷
(PR²
seats+½)
Votes÷
(FPTP
seats+½)
+Votes
for +1
PR² seat
Conservative 11,334,726 128,476.0 347.47 347 331 +16 32,618 34,192 35,105
Labour 9,347,324 87,372.5 236.30 236 232 +4 39,524 40,204 31,099
UKIP 3,881,099 15,062.9 40.74 41 1 +40 93,520 2,587,399 50,574
Liberal Democrat 2,415,862 5,836.4 15.78 16 8 +8 146,416 284,219 77,317
Scottish National Party 1,454,436 2,115.4 5.72 6 56 −50 223,759 25,742 123,219
Green 1,156,149 1,336.7 3.62 4 1 +3 256,922 770,766 151,166
Democratic Unionist P. 184,260 34.0 0.09 0 8 −8 368,520 21,678 451,604
Plaid Cymru 181,704 33.0 0.09 0 3 −3 363,408 51,915 453,423
Sinn Fein 176,232 31.1 0.08 0 4 −4 352,464 39,163 457,349
Ulster Unionist Party 114,935 13.2 0.04 0 2 −2 229,870 45,974 504,379
Social Democratic
& Labour Party
99,809 10.0 0.03 0 3 −3 199,618 28,517 516,872
Independent 98,711 9.7 0.03 0 1 −1 197,422 65,807 517,793
Alliance 61,556 3.8 0.01 0 0 0 123,112 123,112 550,092
Others, totalled 189,738 2.3 0.01 0 0 0

Of course this counter-factual can’t be perfectly fair. Under PR-Squared all the parties, including the regional ones, would have stood everywhere, including the otherwise uncontested Speaker’s seat. So the sub-national parties would have done slightly better than suggested here.

Data source: the Guardian (being more complete than, even though slightly different to, the BBC).

Relative to the current system of FPTP, the effect on the two largest parties would be modest. But compare UKIP and the SNP. UKIP had 2.67× as many votes as the SNP, but the current electoral system gave the SNP 56× as many seats. Doubtless the SNP could construct arguments about why this is legitimate, but not arguments likely to persuade neutral observers. Compare to PR-Squared, under which a party cannot have both fewer votes and more seats. Yes, under PR-Squared the votes per seat are not identical (antepenultimate column), but that is deliberate, to penalise slightly the small parties and thereby encourage coalitions to be formed before the election.

The last column of the table illustrates the voters’ incentives. It shows how many more votes a party would need for its unrounded PR-Squared seat count to be +1 higher. To gain one seat, smaller parties need more votes than do larger parties (sometimes excepting the largest party). Consider the position of a voter who is willing to vote for either the Conservative party or for UKIP. One more vote for the Conservative party is worth +135105 of a seat. One more vote for UKIP is worth +150574 of a seat. A Conservative vote is 1.44× as powerful as a UKIP vote. So if 1.44 Conservative seats would be preferred to 1.0 UKIP seats, vote Conservative. But if the relative fondness for UKIP is sufficient that 1.0 UKIP seats would be preferred to 1.44 Conservative seats, vote UKIP. The equivalent ratio between Labour and the Liberal Democrats is 2.49× and between Labour and the SNP is 3.96×. Under PR-Squared life would be harder for small parties than for large, but not impossibly hard.

Hypthetical coalitions in the 2015 UK general election

The previous table shows the result of the 2015 UK general election under PR-Squared, assuming that everything else had stayed the same. Which, of course, it wouldn’t. Indeed, the purpose of PR-Squared is that it doesn’t: the purpose is to encourage pre-election coalition-making rather than post-election. Let’s further demonstrate this incentive by considering two possible pre-election coalitions.

We start with a ‘Devolution Party’, presumably favouring the de-centralisation of the UK state. Assume that the Liberal Democrats, the Scottish National Party, Plaid Cymru and the SD&LP formed such a coalition. Omitting some irrelevant rows, that might have looked like the following.

Party Votes Votes^2
(billions)
PR² seats
unrounded
PR² seats
rounded
FPTP
seats
PR²−
FPTP
seats
Votes÷
(PR²
seats+½)
Votes÷
(FPTP
seats+½)
+Votes
for +1
PR² seat
Conservative 11,334,726 128,476.0 322.21 322 331 −9 35,146 34,192 34,932
Labour 9,347,324 87,372.5 219.12 219 232 −13 42,585 40,204 32,195
‘Devolution Party’
(LibDem + SNP + Green
+ Plaid Cymru + SDL&P)
5,307,960 28,174.4 70.66 71 71 0 74,237 74,237 42,048
UKIP 3,881,099 15,062.9 37.78 38 1 +37 100,808 2,587,399 54,249
Others, totalled 825,432 94.1 0.24 0 15 −15

Forming that coalition before the election, making it visible to the electorate, has taken its PR-Squared seats from 26 to 71. PR-Squared rewards an earlier coalition agreement.

And a Lib-Lab coalition would have had more votes than the Conservatives, and hence more seats, even if not quite a majority.

Party Votes Votes^2
(billions)
PR² seats
unrounded
PR² seats
rounded
FPTP
seats
PR²−
FPTP
seats
Votes÷
(PR²
seats+½)
Votes÷
(FPTP
seats+½)
+Votes
for +1
PR² seat
Lib-Lab Coalition 11,763,186 138,372.5 315.03 315 240 +75 37,284 48,911 36,281
Conservative 11,334,726 128,476.0 292.50 293 331 −38 38,619 34,192 35,272
UKIP 3,881,099 15,062.9 34.29 34 1 +33 112,496 2,587,399 59,381
Scottish National Party 1,454,436 2,115.4 4.82 5 56 −51 264,443 25,742 145,121
Green 1,156,149 1,336.7 3.04 3 1 +2 330,328 770,766 177,516
Others, totalled 1,106,945 137.1 0.31 0 21 −21

However, a coalition cannot be an entire sham. Two criteria are relevant. First, in any constituency a party may put forward at most one candidate. So the parties trying to form a coalition need to agree on a single candidate in each constituency. Without this much agreement, a putative coalition is no such thing.

Second, a coalition must convince voters. Some might; some won’t. As an example of a coalition that failed to convince the UK electorate, go back to the 1997 general election. There was a coalition between a pro-business pro-efficiency grouping, and a euro-sceptic grouping. This coalition was called ‘The Conservative Party’, and the electorate didn’t like it. But in 2015 a coalition of left to centre-left pro-devolution parties might have the internal coherence to convince the electorate. PR-Squared rewards the honesty of showing that coalition to the electorate, agreements and warts and all.

This honesty would have other advantages. After the 2010 election the Liberal Democrats went into coalition with the Conservatives. The Conservatives were much the larger of the two parties, so did most of the governing. LibDem voters, many of whom saw themselves as at least partly anti-Conservative, afterwards seemed appalled to have ‘voted for’ a mostly-Conservative government. If this coalition had been formed before the 2010 election, then the 2015 election might have been much less of a disaster for the LibDems. Much less.

By-elections

By-elections are slightly more awkward under PR-squared than under FPTP. If a seat should become empty, there are two obvious possibilities:

This second possibility requires care. PR-Squared gives parties an incentive to negotiate coalitions before an election, and to court votes without regard to geography; it gives candidates an incentive to encourage both the local and the national votes; and gives voters an incentive to vote for a party with a realistic chance of forming a government. Care must be taken to ensure that the rules about by-elections do not create any unwanted new incentives.

In the UK, there has been an armed terrorist and racketeering organisation with a political front. Such support as that front has always been geographically narrow, and under FPTP it wins only a small number of constituencies, usually four. Under PR-Squared, it is unlikely that it would win any seats. But in certain constituencies it might win a local by-election. Its terrorist branch has been inactive since September 2001—may it stay that way. But the rules should not create an incentive for such organisations to ‘cause’ a by-election. So death by murder must not cause a by-election. But if resignations cause a by-election, then the terrorists would have an incentive to kill the sitting MP’s children one by one, until the MP is ‘persuaded’ to resign. These are not incentives that an electoral system should be creating. So, if there are to be FPTP-style by-elections, they should be triggered only by the death from natural causes of a sitting MP†3.

Advantages of PR-Squared

Hence PR-Squared has many advantages.

— Julian D. A. Wiseman
London, September 2001 and 11th May 2015
www.jdawiseman.com


Further reading

Footnotes

†1 Also known as the method of odd numbers, Webster’s method, and the method of Saint-Lagüe. The pre-2001 definition of PR-Squared rounded by the Largest Remainder rule: the difference between the two will only very rarely be more than one seat for any party.

†2 We counter-factually assume that the vote totals would be the same under PR-Squared as under FPTP, as such an assumption is near enough to be true for these purposes. However, there is one particular difficulty with mapping FPTP results onto PR-Squared: under FPTP, not all parties stand in all seats. This is because the parties have no incentive to stand where there is no chance of winning. But for completeness PR-Squared needs a rule to cover the case in which, in a particular constituency, no seat-winning party put forward a candidate (i.e., all the candidates are from small local parties). However, whilst there ought to be a rule, in practice, the parties’ incentive is such that this rule would never be needed. Parties want votes, and any party with a chance of winning seats anywhere will want every vote it can get in any constituency. But there should be a rule nonetheless, and it would work as follows. In each constituency in which a party did not put forward a candidate, it is assumed that the party did put forward a candidate (a ‘deemed null candidate’), but that this candidate received zero votes; and any seat won by a deemed null candidate would remain empty.

†3 This also raises the issue of the death of a candidate just before an election. What should happen if a candidate dies after being nominated but before the polling date? To withdraw the candidate from the poll denies voters the opportunity to vote for that party, which seems unfair. The natural course is to allow the dead candidate to remain a candidate: for electoral purposes the candidate will be deemed to have died immediately after the election. If the dead candidate is elected, the by-election rules then come into play.


Main index Top About author