Main index Electoral System index About author

Valid HTML 4.01 Transitional

Apportionment, or How to Round Seat Numbers

Julian D. A. Wiseman

Abstract: It is desired to allocate a fixed number of seats proportional to some numbers (such as votes, population or even votes squared). If each entity is to receive an integer number of seats, then the allocations must be rounded. There are several ways to do this, with interesting and surprising properties.

Contents: Publication History, Introduction, Largest Remainder, Webster, Jefferson, Quotient methods, d’Hondt, Saint-Laguë, Modified Saint-Laguë, Danish, Imperiali, Breaching quota, Other systems, Statistics, with 659 seats, PR-Squared

Publication history: only here. Usual disclaimer and copyright terms apply.


Introduction

In many electoral systems seats are assigned proportionally: in PR-classic, in proportion to the votes; in PR-Squared, to the squares of the votes. For example, imagine that 11 seats are to be divided in the proportions 59:26:16:7. The ‘correct’ number of seats for each party would be 6.01, 2.65, 1.63 and 0.71. However, seats have to be whole numbers; how are these to be rounded? There are several different apportionment schemes, none of which are perfect. The main such schemes are described here, along with their features and flaws.

Largest Remainder

The ‘largest-remainder’ method, also known as the ‘Hamilton’ method, is perhaps the most intuitive. Start by calculating the ‘unrounded’ seats, also known as the quota. These are the 6.01, 2.65, 1.63 and 0.71 already cited. Round down. Each party receives at least that many seats: 6, 2, 1 and 0. Two seats remain to be allocated, and these two seats are allocated to the parties with the largest remainders, in this example the 0.65 and the 0.71, for a final seat allocation of 6, 3, 1, and 1. In summary:


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

Quota

Seats
Largest remainder 592616 7 11 6.0092.6481.6300.713  6  3  1  1 

So far, so fair. However, there is a problem. Consider allocating 4 seats in the ratio 5:3:1. The unrounded seats are 2.222, 1.333 and 0.444, for a preliminary allocation of 2:1:0. Only 1 seat remains to be allocated; the largest remainder is 0.444, for a final allocation 2:1:1. But what if, instead, there were 5 seats to be allocated? Unrounded seats of 2.777, 1.666, and 0.555, give a preliminary allocation of 2:1:0; the two largest remainders are 0.777 and 0.666, for a final score of 3:2:0.


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

Quota

Seats
Largest
remainder
 5 3 1 4 2.2221.3330.444  2  1  1 
5 2.7771.6660.555  3  2  0 

Compare 2:1:1 to 3:2:0! An increase in the total number of seats has caused the smallest party to lose a seat. Surely the same share of a larger pie shouldn’t be smaller?

In the US, each state sends a number of Representatives, the number being proportional to its population. After the 1880 census it was observed that a House size of 299 would allow Alabama 8 seats, but a size of 300 would reduce this to 7. Hence this feature of the largest-remainder method is known as the ‘Alabama Paradox’.

Indeed, largest remainder has another undesirable feature. Imagine that there are three ‘serious’ parties, genuine contenders for government, and that there is also a minor party, too small to win seats. To be specific, perhaps imagine that this minor party is the UK’s Official Monster Raving Loony Party: amusing, but not a government in waiting. In proportions 50:17:4:0 a total of 11 seats are to be allocated; giving unrounded totals of 7.75 : 2.63 : 0.62 : 0.00, and hence a seat allocation of 8:3:0:0. But what if the minor party had managed to rouse a small number of voters from their slumbers? The results, summarised in the following table, are surprising.


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

Quota

Seats
Largest
remainder
5017 4 0 11 7.752.630.620.00  8  3  0  0 
 1 7.642.600.610.15  8  2  1  0 
 2 7.532.560.600.30  7  3  1  0 

The tiny party does not win a seat in any of these scenarios. But nonetheless, its acquiring a small number of votes can affect the allocation of the seats between the non-tiny parties. Note that in the top row the third party is to be assigned 4/61 of the seats, and receives none, but in the second row is to receive a slightly smaller 4/62 of the seats, but receives 1.

The Webster method

The Webster method proceeds by finding a divisor, l. Start with the target proportions; divide each by l, and round to the nearest whole number. If l is too low, this will give too many seats. If l too high, too few. Of the values of l that give the correct number of seats, choose the largest. So, in the 59:26:16:7 example, choose l to be 32/3, which gives unrounded seats of 5.53125, 2.4375, 1.5, and 0.65625, which round to 6, 2, 2 and 1.


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

l

Unrounded

Seats
L. R. 592616 7 11   6.0092.6481.6300.713  6  3  1  1 
Webster 32/3 5.531252.43751.50.65625  6  2  2  1 

The Jefferson method

The Jefferson method is similar to the Webster method. Again, start with the target proportions; and again divide each by l, but rounding down instead of to the nearest. To compare this to the Webster method, let us take a minimal example, in which two parties are to split 3 seats in the ratio 4:1. The Webster divisor l would be 2, giving seats of 2 and 0.5 which round to 2 and 1. But Jefferson rounds down, so l must be smaller, in this case 4/3, giving seats of 3 and 0.75, which round to 3 and 0. In summary:


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

l

Unrounded

Seats
Webster  4 1 3 2 20.5  2  1 
Jefferson 4/3 30.75  3  0 

This result is typical: Jefferson advantages large parties more than Webster, and disadvantages small parties, a pattern which can also be seen in the now-familiar 11-seat 59:26:16:7 example:


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

l

Unrounded

Seats
Jefferson 592616 7 11 59/7 73.0851.8990.831  7  3  1  0 
L. R.   6.0092.6481.6300.713  6  3  1  1 
Webster 32/3 5.531252.43751.50.65625  6  2  2  1 

Quotient methods

Quotient methods perform the allocation one seat at a time. Start with the target proportions, and allocate the first seat to the party with the largest such proportion. This party now has a seat, and so its target proportion is divided by a divisor. What divisor?

d’Hondt

The d’Hondt rule says that the divisors are simply one more than the number of seats that party already has. The table shows this process at work in the 59:26:16:7 example. The first seat goes to the largest party, and its 59-part share is then replaced by a 59/2 = 29.50 part share. It is still the largest party (the largest party is shown in bold), so gains the next seat, and its share replaced by 59/3 = 19.6666, which means that the third seat to be allocated goes to the second-largest party. The process is continued until all 11 seats are allocated.

QuotientsSeats
59261671000
29.50261672000
19.67261672100
19.67131673100
14.75131673110
14.7513874110
11.8013874210
11.808.67875210
9.838.67876210
8.438.67876310
8.436.50877310

This example used the d’Hondt rule, with divisors 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, etc. The d’Hondt rule always gives exactly the same allocation of seats as the Jefferson method.

Saint-Laguë

The Saint-Laguë rule uses divisors 1, 3, 5, 7, 9, etc; this is equivalent to the Webster method:

QuotientsSeats
59261671000
19.67261671100
19.678.671672100
11.808.671672110
11.808.675.3373110
8.438.675.3373210
8.435.205.3374210
6.565.205.3374211
6.565.205.332.335211
5.365.205.332.336211
4.545.205.332.336221

Modified Saint-Laguë

Other divisor rules are possible, including Modified Saint-Laguë (1.4, 3, 5, 7, 9, etc):

QuotientsSeats
42.1418.5711.4351000
19.6718.5711.4352000
11.8018.5711.4352100
11.808.6711.4353100
8.438.6711.4353110
8.438.675.3353210
8.435.205.3354210
6.565.205.3355210
5.365.205.3356210
4.545.205.3356220
4.545.203.2056320

Danish

Danish (1, 4, 7, 10, 13, etc):

QuotientsSeats
59261671000
14.75261671100
14.756.501671110
14.756.50472110
8.436.50473110
5.906.50473111
5.906.5041.753211
5.903.7141.754211
4.543.7141.755211
3.693.7141.755221
3.693.712.291.755321

Imperiali

and Imperiali (1, 1.5, 2, 2.5, 3, 3.5, etc):

QuotientsSeats
59261671000
39.33261672000
29.50261673000
23.60261673100
23.6017.331674100
19.6717.331675100
16.8617.331675200
16.86131676200
14.75131676210
14.751310.6777210
13.111310.6778210

So, let us bring all these examples together showing the order in which seats were allocated for the quotient methods:


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

l

Working

Seats
Imperiali 592616 7 11   A A A B A A B A C A A  8  2  1  0 
d’Hondt / Jefferson 59/7 A A B A C A B A A B A  7  3  1  0 
Modified Saint-Laguë   A A B A C B A A A C B  6  3  2  0 
L. R. / Hamilton   6.0092.6481.6300.713  6  3  1  1 
Saint-Laguë / Webster 32/3 A B A C A B A D A A C  6  2  2  1 
Danish   A B C A A D B A A C B  5  3  2  1 

It can be seen immediately that Imperiali is the most favourable to large parties. Imperiali has slowly-increasing divisors (1, 1.5, 2, 2.5, ...); large parties gain many seats before their quotients are reduced below those of the smaller parties. In contrast, the Danish divisors (1, 4, 7, 10, ...) increase so fast that large parties are quickly cut down — much to the benefit of smaller parties.

Breaching quota

In the 59:26:16:7 example, the quota (unrounded) seat allocations were 6.009, 2.648, 1.630 and 0.713. In this example only two of the above systems ‘breached quota’, that is, gave a seat allocation smaller than rounded-down quota or larger than this plus 1. However, any of these systems other than Hamilton / Largest Remainder can breach quota, as evidenced in the following table:


Method
Target
proportions
Seat
total

Quota

Seats
Imperiali  3 1 1  3 1.80.60.6   3  0  0  
d’Hondt / Jefferson  5 1 1  4 2.8570.5710.571   4  0  0  
Modified Saint-Laguë  7 1 1  5 3.8890.5560.556   5  0  0  
Saint-Laguë / Webster 14 3 1 1 8 5.8951.2630.4210.421  7  1  0  0 
Danish  9 1 1  5 4.0910.4550.455   3  1  1  

Other systems

There are two frequently seen contexts in which seats have to be assigned proportional to some number. The first context, in which we are interested here, is following an election. The second is the assignment of seats to a geographical region. The difference is that, usually, it is required that every region has at least one seat, however small. Applying such a system to post-election assignments would ensure that every party gets a seat.

An example is the ‘Adams method’ of apportionment, which is similar to the Webster and Jefferson methods, except that the number of seats is rounded up. Another, the ‘method of equal proportions’, again uses a divisor, but rounds up only if the number of seats to be allocated exceeds the geometric average of itself rounded down and itself plus 1 rounded down.

Because the US constitution says merely that the House of Representatives “shall be apportioned among the several States according to their respective numbers”, and that “each State shall have at least one Representative”, these systems have been of interest to the US courts. An explanation of the 1991 and 1992 cases challenging the use of the method of equal proportions can be found here.

Statistics

In order to acquire a better feel for the properties of the six systems under review, a simple statistical analysis has been performed. We have considered a 6-party election, in which seats are to be proportional to votes. The relative sizes of the votes of the parties are constrained, so the number of votes received by the i’th largest party, divided by the number of votes received by the i+1’th largest party, is in the range 3^½ to 2^¼. In other words, each party is between 18.92% and 73.2% larger than the next-largest party. We then ignore any vote distribution that causes any of the 6 electoral systems under review to have a draw.

For 11 seats we consider the 82,837,504 vote distributions running from 8:6:5:4:3:2 to 152:108:78:63:44:33. For each vote distribution we calculate the average number of seats won by the largest party, by the second-largest, the third-largest, etc. For each of the six methods under consideration, we observe the difference between that method and the average. We calculate both an average difference, and the standard deviation of that difference. The following charts show the average differences, and their standard deviation.

Relative performance of apportionment methods given 11 seats

It is immediately apparent that Imperiali greatly favours the larger parties. Indeed, on average the largest party does 0.9 seats better under Imperiali than under d’Hondt / Jefferson. Jefferson also favours larger parties, though much less than Imperiali. For the middle two parties Jefferson is more consistent than Imperiali, as measured by its standard deviation from its average behaviour. In this model Modified Saint-Laguë most favours the fourth largest party, though is the most random in its treatment of the smallest party. Largest Remainder / Hamilton and Saint-Laguë / Webster are very similar, with the former being 0.06 seats more generous to the largest party, and 0.1 seats less to the smallest. The standard deviations of their differences from the average are also close. Danish favours small parties, though by less, and less randomly, than Imperiali favours the large.

A similar pattern occurs with a 659-seat constituency:

Relative performance of apportionment methods given 659 seats

except that Modified Saint-Laguë, Largest Remainder / Hamilton and Saint-Laguë / Webster are so close as to be almost indistinguishable, with Hamilton being (by an edge) the most random.

Quota breaches can also be addressed statistically. The following table shows the average size of breaches of upper quota (top item in each cell), and of lower quota (lower item). A blank indicates that no breaches were observed; therefore ‘0.00’ indicates that they were present but rare. Imperiali frequently breaches upper quota for the large parties, and lower quota for the small. Jefferson also over-helps the largest party, though less than Imperiali. Largest Remainder never breaches quota (by construction), the others do so, but rarely.

Quota breaches with 659 seatsAverage extent of breaches of upper quota
Average extent of breaches of lower quota
Party size:Largest    Smallest
Danish 
-0.00
 
-0.00
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Saint-Laguë / Webster0.00
-0.00
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Largest Remainder / Hamilton 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Modified Saint-Laguë0.00
-0.00
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
d’Hondt / Jefferson0.06
 
0.00
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
Imperiali0.87
 
0.14
 
0.00
 
 
-0.01
 
-0.21
 
-0.45

PR-Squared

So what does all this imply for PR-Squared?

Julian D. A. Wiseman, July 2001


Main index Top About author